Skip to main content

EU-UK Trade negotiations.

The UK trades with the EU at an enormous deficit.  The UK also has a huge deficit in the payment of profits, rents and dividends to the EU.  The combination of the deficits in trade and financial transactions has led to a very large balance of payments current account deficit with the EU of £119 billion in 2019.  It will be shown below that this deficit is dangerous for the long term health of the UK economy and suggestions are made for any trade deal with the EU.

Before proceeding further it should be made clear that the large trade deficit with the EU is not due to a failure of UK exporters.  It is due to the steady acquisition of UK companies by EU owners (25% of UK production value is EU owned) and the ease with which parts etc. can be imported from the EU by EU companies (See The Eurozone Trojan Horse for further details).

Should we be worried about such a huge deficit?  The deficit with the EU is real and is financed by a trade surplus of £24 billion with non-EU countries and through borrowing by UK banks and companies. 

Dekle et al summarised the effect of these deficits succinctly for the case of the USA:

”According to our static analysis, the main welfare cost of eliminating the current account deficit is simply the loss of the free lunch, i.e. the loss of goods that we currently consume but do not pay for until later. That cost is on the order of six percent of GDP.” UNBALANCED TRADE Robert Dekle et al

In other words the deficit is paid for by our children. The financial account in the UK is also in deficit so there is no magical "invisibles" money to bail out the deficits. Our trade deficit is simply generating debt.

The effect of a continuing deficit is worse than a one off deficit because as the indebtedness of a country increases its creditworthiness decreases so there comes a moment of reckoning when it suddenly becomes very difficult to borrow money except at very high interest rates.  The UK is not in this position at the moment but if it continues to have a current account deficit of about £80 billion a year for another decade it will be on the edge of a sudden economic collapse.  As can be seen below, the current account deficit with the EU is enormous.

(Source data: Current Account with the EUCurrent Account with non-EU. )

Governments that run persistent current account deficits are gambling.  The gamble is that by the time the economy collapses they will not be in government. 

The total UK external debt (borrowing from overseas) is over £6 trillion:

(Source data: UK External Debt )

This level of debt is largely due to borrowing to pay for the current account deficit.

The UK Government debt is  currently £1876 bn and the external government debt is near £800 bn.  The interest repayments on the government debt alone are £41.6bn for 2019-20

 

The external debt of the UK is very high by international standards but currently there is little risk of lenders getting nervous.  Real problems might arise in ten years time at the current rate of UK debt accumulation and these deficits steadily devalue the currency in the long term, reducing our ability to repay loans in foreign currencies.

Over half of the UK current account deficit with the EU is a trade deficit.

Source data: UK-EU Trade in Goods and Services, UK-non-EU Trade in Goods and Services ).

Given the parlous state of UK-EU trade the UK will need to take great care in its trade negotiations.  Trade negotiations should have two aims: to increase bilateral trade and avoid large deficits.  There is clearly the need for a "circuit breaker" to address the UK-EU deficits before we even consider a trade deal.

The simplest circuit breaker is to trade with the EU on WTO terms for a few years.  The introduction of tariffs on EU goods and services will probably lead to the substitution of UK made goods and services.  The substitution of domestic for foreign produce seems to be the rule rather than the exception and this results in GDP growth being decoupled from tariffs.

Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic's Guide to the Cross-National Evidence


This lack of relationship between tariffs and growth should give the UK confidence in the WTO scenario for Brexit.

But what of the various predictions for disaster if the UK leaves the EU on WTO terms?  These predictions were based on "gravity models" and used GDP rather than GDP per head as the measure of the effect of a WTO Brexit.  In the excellent paper by Coutts et al 2018, "How the economics profession got it wrong on Brexit" a group of Remain voting, Cambridge University economists investigated how so many of the predictions for 2016 onward have been wrong.  The most important finding of these economists was that there were flaws in both the application of gravity model results to a Brexit context and in the knock-on impacts from trade to  productivity.  The  flaws  always  had  the  result  of  exaggerating  the negative impact of Brexit. 

The Treasury gravity model approach  involved  analysing  trade  flows  between  around  120  countries  over  a  65-year period and estimating an equation relating bilateral trade to the size of the two economies  in  each  trade  pair,  their  distance  apart  and  other  factors  such  as  a  common  language. This produced a gravity equation that was used to determine the effects of proximity to trade.  The effect was highly positive over the whole EU but the Treasury missed the fact that the UK was an outlier.  In the case of the UK the effect of proximity was negative.  The punch line of the re-evaluation of the gravity models by the author was:

"The  UK  is  the  only  EU  state,  other  than  Malta,  which  exports more to non-EU countries than to other EU member states. UK exports of goods to the EU have usually been well below the levels predicted by these gravity model equations. Instead of the Treasury’s average impact [of EU membership] across all 28 EU  member  states  of  around  115%  extra  trade,  the  increase  in  the  UK  alone  appears  to  be  much  lower,  in  the  range  20-25%."

Once the correct figures are used for the effects of proximity on the trade in goods, and modern data on the effect of proximity on services are included, Coutts et al 2018 predict a 2-5% decrease in international trade with a WTO Brexit.  We would expect domestic substitution for these losses and also acquisition of goods from cheaper sources abroad.

All of this means that the UK should be sanguine about a WTO Brexit.  There is certainly no need to give up UK territory, such as the fishing grounds, to buy free trade.

A mobile friendly version of this article is available at: There and Where: The UK-EU Trade Negotiations

Postscript: The basic problem is that the UK economy was becoming a regional economy within the Single Market.  As a Scot will tell you, the only cure for the economy being owned by people who are based hundreds of miles away is independence.


19/10/2020

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

The Falklands have always been Argentine - Las Malvinas son Argentinas

"The Falklands have always been Argentine" is taught to every Argentine child as a matter of faith.  What was Argentina during the time when it "always" possessed Las Malvinas?  In this article I will trace the history of Argentina in the context of its physical and political relationship with "Las Malvinas", the Falkland Islands.  The Argentine claim to the Falkland Islands dates from a brief episode in 1831-32 so it is like Canada claiming the USA despite two centuries of separate development. This might sound like ancient history but Argentina has gone to war for this ancient claim so the following article is well worth reading. For a summary of the legal case see: Las Malvinas: The Legal Case Argentina traces its origins to Spanish South America when it was part of the Viceroyalty of the Rio del Plata.  The Falklands lay off the Viceroyalty of Peru, controlled by the Captain General of Chile.  In 1810 the Falklands were far from the geographical b

Practical Idealism by Richard Nicolaus Coudenhove-Kalergi

Coudenhove-Kalergi was a pioneer of European integration. He was the founder and President for 49 years of the Paneuropean Union. His parents were Heinrich von Coudenhove-Kalergi, an Austro-Hungarian diplomat, and Mitsuko Aoyama, the daughter of an oil merchant, antiques-dealer, and huge landowner family in Tokyo. His "Pan-Europa" was published in 1923 and contained a membership form for the Pan-Europa movement. Coudenhove-Kalergi's movement held its first Congress in Vienna in 1926. In 1927 the French Prime Minister, Aristide Briand was elected honorary president.  Personalities attending included: Albert Einstein, Thomas Mann and Sigmund Freud. Figures who later became central to founding the EU, such as Konrad Adenauer became members . His basic idea was that democracy was a transitional stage that leads to rule by a new aristocracy that is largely taken from the Jewish "master race" (Kalergi's terminology). His movement was reviled by Hitler and H

Membership of the EU: pros and cons

5th December 2013, update May 2016 Nigel Lawson, ex-Chancellor of the Exchequer,  recently criticised the UK membership of the EU , the media has covered his mainstream view as if he is a bad boy starting a fight in the school playground, but is he right about the EU? What has changed that makes EU membership a burning issue?  What has changed is that the 19 countries of the Eurozone are now seeking political union to escape their financial problems.   Seven further EU countries have signed up to join the Euro but the British and Danish have opted out.  The EU is rapidly becoming two blocks - the 26 and Britain and Denmark.   Lawson's fear was that if Britain stays in the EU it will be isolated and dominated by a Eurozone bloc that uses "unified representation of the euro area" , so acting like a single country which controls 90% of the vote in the EU with no vetoes available to the UK in most decisions.  The full plans for Eurozone political union ( EMU Stage